The Theory of Investment Value: Four Enduring Takeaways on Dividend Investing from John Burr Williams
Today’s historically low interest rates and investors’ flight to safety have combined to raise interest in dividend-paying stocks. While studies of the efficacy of dividend-investing strategies have been mixed (see Fama and French 1988 and Ang and Bekaert 2006), dividend investing remains a popular strategy. Indeed, this heightened enthusiasm is reflected in the performance of dividend-paying stocks, which have handily outpaced broad market indices over the past year. As such, it only seems appropriate to revisit an investing classic that first provided investors with a theoretical framework for determining the intrinsic value of stocks based on their dividends: John Burr Williams’s The Theory of Investment Value.
Just as Benjamin Graham is considered to be the father of value investing, John Burr Williams rightfully deserves to be recognized as the progenitor of dividend investing. The influence of his seminal work, first published in 1938, has been widespread, and today the book remains as relevant as ever.
Here are four of the most important takeaways:
1. Focus on Dividends, Not Earnings.
Williams was a security analyst who sought a better understanding of what caused the stock market crash of 1929 and the subsequent Great Depression. He enrolled as a PhD student at Harvard, and his thesis, which was to explore the intrinsic value of common stock, was published as The Theory of Investment Value. Breaking with commonly held beliefs at the time, the crux of Williams’ theory was that the intrinsic value of a company was equal to the present value of its future dividends, not earnings. “Earnings are only a means to an end,” Williams argued, “and the means should not be mistaken for the end. Therefore, we must say that a stock derives its value from its dividends, not its earnings.
He illustrated this concept with a poem:
A cow for her milk
A hen for her eggs,
And a stock, by heck,
For her dividends.
An orchard for fruit,
Bees for their honey,
And stocks, besides,
For their dividends.
In a review of Williams’ book published in The Journal of Political Economy, Ben Graham, alluding to the speculative atmosphere pervasive on Wall Street at the time, wrote: “The emphasis on the primacy of dividends and the insistence that the value of reinvested earnings is to be found only in increased dividends sound a much-needed warning to Wall Streeters.”
For companies without dividends, Williams theorized that all retained earnings should ultimately become dividends. Upon maturity, a company should begin distributing its earnings as dividends. Williams wrote: “If earnings not paid out in dividends are all successfully reinvested, then these earnings should produce dividends later; if not, then they are money lost. In short, a stock is worth only what you can get out of it.”
2. Investment versus Speculation.
Williams shared many of Graham’s views when it came to drawing a distinction between investing and speculating. Williams defined an investor as “a buyer interested in dividends, or coupons and principal,” and a speculator as “a buyer interested in the resale price” alone. Williams thought the volatility of the stock market did not accurately reflect the capacity of companies to pay dividends, and he saw the 1929 stock market crash as “a serious indictment of past practice” of investment analysis. He asserted that if there had been agreement among analysts regarding the “proper criteria of value,” the wild price swings experienced in the crash and its aftermath might have been avoided. With his book, Williams hoped to encourage more true investing and less speculation.
Despite the stock market’s volatility, both Williams and Graham took issue with the “casino capitalism” theory espoused by John Maynard Keynes in his famous General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936), which pointed, critically, to the boom and bust cycles of stocks. “It is usually agreed that casinos should, in the public interest, be inaccessible and expensive,” Keynes wrote, “And perhaps the same is true of Stock Exchanges.” In contrast, Williams and Graham both saw the benefits of free markets but, importantly, also the need for rigorous analysis in the determination of intrinsic value.
3. Lasting Influence.
Among the first to advocate for a theory of valuation based on discounted cash flow, Williams referred to his forecasting approach as “algebraic budgeting,” and he undoubtedly influenced the thinking of some of the greatest investment theoreticians and practitioners of the past century.
In fact, Williams’ work provided the theoretical foundation for what became the Gordon growth model, named after Myron J. Gordon. In “Dividends, Earnings, and Stock Prices” (1959), Gordon wrote: “The distinguished theoretical book on investment value by J.B. Williams contains several chapters devoted to the application of the theory, but his empirical work is in the tradition of the investment analyst’s approach.”
And Warren Buffett, in Berkshire Hathaway’s 1992 Annual Report, wrote the following: “In The Theory of Investment Value, written over 50 years ago, John Burr Williams set forth the equation for value, which we condense here: The value of any stock, bond, or business today is determined by the cash inflows and outflows—discounted at an appropriate interest rate—that can be expected to occur during the remaining life of the asset.” Though Buffett may have tweaked Williams’ theory slightly, his investment success serves as a testament to the validity of Williams’ work.
4. On Government, Socialism, and Taxes.
Williams was not a fan of big government. In a chapter titled “Taxes and Socialism,” he made clear his belief that government was a poor steward of the economy. Williams argued that taxes were a drag on savings, investment, earnings, and ultimately, the value of securities. In Williams’ view, government deficits carried with them the threat of higher taxes, and “the mere prospect of higher taxes is sufficient to discourage investment in capital goods.” Williams further warned that the redistributive nature of excessive taxation, and government control of key industries, would put the United States on a path toward socialism.
Politics aside, Williams and The Theory of Investment Value offer timeless lessons on the concept of intrinsic value, the importance of dividends, and the value of a long-term perspective. In an era of heightened volatility and low investment returns, these lessons are more important than ever.
If you liked this post, don’t forget to subscribe to the Enterprising Investor.
All posts are the opinion of the author. As such, they should not be construed as investment advice, nor do the opinions expressed necessarily reflect the views of CFA Institute or the author’s employer.
I appreciate his work in investment and security analysis. Without him we won’t be able to calculate the intrinsic value of a security but his perception on government is totally wrong. Without tax how the government going to run the company? Look at subprime and liquidity crisis, these are the result of government governance! The rich are irresponsible and they are chasing for profit without considering the cost to society! Without a government there won’t be any middles class left!
Unfortunately, this commentary doesn’t take into account current tax policy. Since dividends are not deductible for corporations, dividends are taxed twice (first at the corporate level and then at the investor level). Thus, all other things being equal, investors should prefer stocks that do not pay dividends.
Interesting article. I also commend the work of Williams. However I believe it is appropriate for government to charge and collect tax to promote public good which capitalist-inclined investors won’t. I also think that as long as the after-tax return makes sense to an investor capital investment will continue.
By the way, if I put a certain amount into an investment (or savings instrument) with the goal of getting an increase (or return) after a period, does it matter whether the return came only as capital gains or dividend+capital gains.
I agree that Government is needed. However, I also think that it should be controlled, and not by selfish, greedy politicians. Foxes watching the Hen house, theory. There should be some kind of cap on what “We the People” pay. There should also be constraints on what the government spends (both Limits & Where they spend money). I don’t think a progressive tax system is Fair. I think a Flat tax or Fair Tax should be implemented.