Enterprising Investor
Practical analysis for investment professionals
10 January 2013

Time Series Analysis, Taxing the Wealthy, and GDP Growth

Although the language of time series analysis can seem specialized, practitioners can maintain a competitive edge by knowing how to interpret the results of time-series studies. In finance, time series are ubiquitous, and so knowledge of such things as what unit roots are or how to control for heteroskedasticity can be useful in evaluating reports. Financial reports make claims with investment relevance, and analysts need to know how to evaluate whether the reports provide solid evidence for claims.

For example, amid all of the political wrangling in DC over tax rates for the wealthiest Americans, a recent paper from the Congressional Research Service, “Taxes and the Economy: An Economic Analysis of the Top Tax Rates Since 1945,” drew the ire of Senate Republicans. In the study, the author, Thomas L. Hungerford, concluded that reduction in the top tax rates has had little association with saving, investment, or productivity growth, but were associated with the increasing concentration of income at the top. This conclusion was not overly popular with that party, so the paper came under fire for some of his methods used (or in this case not used) to support its points.

With sixty observations (years) and time series analysis, it’s as difficult to refute as to support the belief that lower top-tax rates are associated with growth. Hungerford used a standard set of analytical tools, which are nicely explained in Damodar N. Gujarati’s basic econometrics text or Escudero’s “A Primer on Unit Roots and Cointegration.” For time series regression, the series need to be stationary (constant mean, variance, covariance). Hungerford controlled for heteroskedastic (nonconstant variance) and autocorrelated (correlated with themselves over time) error terms, using the Newey-West method. He also tested for unit roots (if the root/slope coefficient on the lagged value of the time series variable is unity, the series is a random walk and nonstationary). By first differencing several variables, Hungerford was able to convert to stationary series. All this follows standard analyst procedures, but the interesting aspect of statistical analysis is that there are always more ways to slice the data.

At the heart of Hungerford’s analysis is the relationship between changes in GDP and changes in the top marginal tax rates. Because he found no significant relationship between these, Hungerford took his analysis as supporting the idea that reduction in the top tax rates has had little association with saving, investment, or productivity growth. What then are the possible criticisms of this type of time series work?

  1. Omitted variable bias. Reduction in the top tax rates is associated with saving, investment, and productivity growth — but the regression coefficient estimate of the top tax rates is biased because of an omitted variable. For that to happen, the omitted variable (say measures of monetary policy) would need to be correlated with the top tax rates and have an effect on economic growth. Although it is doubtful that various measures of monetary policy are correlated with the top statutory tax rate variables used in the analysis, these purported correlations are testable. A further test would be to include one of the various monetary policy variables in the analysis.
  2. Impact or take-effect lag. Reduction in the top tax rates is associated with saving, investment, and productivity growth — but only with a time lag. To check this, one repeats the study to see whether changes in the top tax rates affect the economy after a specified number of years. The impact or take-effect lag is tough to measure with any policy change, and there is an adage that political cycles are shorter than economic ones.
  3. Anticipation effect. Reduction in the top tax rates is associated with saving, investment, and productivity growth — but the tax rate changes are anticipated. If the change is anticipated, the effects of a tax rate change on consumer behavior could begin before the change is effected and extend over some time afterward as consumers adjust their consumption habits.
  4. Insufficient variation of the independent variable. Reduction in the top tax rates is associated with saving, investment, and productivity growth — but the top marginal tax rate (MTR) and the top capital gains tax rate (KTR) have each had only six different values over the roughly 60 years examined. Given just five years in which there is a change in value, the variables (delta)(1 − MTR) and (delta)(1 − KTR) are zero in the vast majority of years. A virtually constant variable cannot be expected to explain year-to-year variation in the response variable, and so there is no surprise that the coefficient on these two variables is close to zero and insignificant.

To be informed consumers of financial reports, analysts must be alert to the challenges of multiple regression with time-series variables. (Because most reports involve such variables, analysts even need to be alert to multiple regressions run without recognition of time series issues.) Our conclusion with the Hungerford article is that the association or lack of association between lower top tax rates and economic growth remains an open question.


Please note that the content of this site should not be construed as investment advice, nor do the opinions expressed necessarily reflect the views of CFA Institute.

Photo credit: ©iStockphoto.com/retrorocket

Tags: , ,

About the Author(s)
Dennis McLeavey, CFA

Dennis McLeavey, CFA, was head of regulator and program recognition, as well as a content director for quantitative methods at CFA Institute. He is professor emeritus of finance and management science at the University of Rhode Island. McLeavey has also served as head of education, EMEA, at CFA Institute and as head of curriculum development for the CFA Program. He is coauthor of Quantitative Investment Analysis, a Wiley text in the CFA Institute Investment Series. He also coauthored Global Investments, Production Planning and Inventory Control, and Operations Research for Management Decisions, and is coeditor of Managing Investor Portfolios. His research has been published in Management Science, the Journal of Operations Research, and the Journal of Portfolio Management, among others. McLeavey has taught at the University of Western Ontario and the University of Rhode Island. He has served as chairperson of the CFA Institute Retirement Investment Policy Committee and as a New York Stock Exchange arbitrator. In 2008, he initiated the CFA Institute Take 15 webcast series. He serves on the Fund Advisory Board for the Global Perspectives Fund at the University of North Carolina Kenan-Flegler Business School, and he oversees the Ram Fund at the University of Rhode Island. McLeavey holds a bachelor’s degree in economics from the University of Western Ontario and a doctorate in production management and industrial engineering, with a minor in mathematics, from Indiana University.

1 thought on “Time Series Analysis, Taxing the Wealthy, and GDP Growth”

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *



By continuing to use the site, you agree to the use of cookies. more information

The cookie settings on this website are set to "allow cookies" to give you the best browsing experience possible. If you continue to use this website without changing your cookie settings or you click "Accept" below then you are consenting to this.

Close