Practical analysis for investment professionals
03 May 2019

Sunset Provisions for Dual-Class Share Structures?

Dual-class share structures take a lot of heat from practitioners and academics alike. When Snap Inc. was preparing for its initial public offering (IPO) in 2017, CalPERS and other institutional investors harshly criticized the company’s move to create a new share class with no voting power. Similarly, before Lyft went public this year, a group of institutional investors unsuccessfully lobbied its board to abandon a proposed dual-class structure.

Why are dual-class share structures so controversial? Because, critics contend, they give the insiders who control the firm disproportionate voting rights relative to their cash flow rights and make it easy for them to take advantage of dispersed outside shareholders. This, in turn, is believed to be correlated with less-efficient corporate decision making and poorer performance over the long term. Indeed, research also suggests that “one share, one vote” weighting is the optimal structure.

Nevertheless, many prominent companies, especially in the tech sector — Google, Facebook, and Lyft among them — have embraced dual-class voting in their IPOs. That such pillars of the modern economy would opt for — if the literature is to be believed — the path of self-sabotage gave us pause and led us to look more closely at the potential benefits of the dual-class structure over a firm’s life cycle.

In our paper, “Sticking around Too Long? Dynamics of the Benefits of Dual-Class Voting,” we examine how the influence, both positive and negative, of a dual-class share structure, net of costs, evolves over a company’s existence. We carefully — often manually — construct a database of more than 900 unique dual-class firms in the United States. The sample spanned almost 50 years, from 1971 through 2015.

Using the data, we show that young dual-class firms — those with less than the sample median of 12 years from their IPOs — have about 7% greater valuation than single-class firms of the same maturity, in the same industry and year, and with similar characteristics.

As they mature, dual-class companies experience approximately 9% greater declines in valuations than their single-class counterparts. What explains such diminishing returns? We found that the principal drivers are deteriorating operating performance, slower innovation rates, and increasing systematic risk.

This evidence suggests that the costs of a dual-class share structure increase significantly as firms evolve, while the benefits of shielding firms from capital market pressure decrease. These findings challenge the dominant view that dual-class voting is suboptimal. Rather, dual-class voting is likely to be optimal for young, fast-growing firms.

So rather than precluding dual-class firms altogether, investors and firms should consider embracing dual-class structures — with defined sunset provisions. The dual-class structure could be in place until a particular event — say, the passing of a fixed period of time — triggered their retirement, or minority shareholders could vote on an extension of the structure at a predetermined time post-IPO.

These provisions are simple to understand and easy to implement. They allow firms and investors to enjoy the advantages of dual-class structures when those advantages are clear — when companies are young and growing fast — while providing a time-consistent way to dismantle them after their time is up.

If you liked this post, don’t forget to subscribe to the Enterprising Investor.


All posts are the opinion of the author. As such, they should not be construed as investment advice, nor do the opinions expressed necessarily reflect the views of CFA Institute or the author’s employer.

Imaged credit: ©Getty Images/Chiara Salvadori


Continuing Education for CFA Institute Members

Select articles are eligible for continuing education (CE) credit. Record credits easily using the CFA Institute Members App, available on iOS and Android.

About the Author(s)
Hyunseob Kim, PhD

Professor Hyunseob Kim is an assistant professor of finance at the Johnson Graduate School of Management. His research covers topics in corporate finance and labor economics, such as the effects of asset and labor market frictions on corporate financial and investment policies and the effects of corporate governance, financial distress, and labor contracts on productivity, wages, and asset reallocations. His work has been published in such leading academic journals in finance and economics as the Review of Financial Studies and the National Tax Journal. He received the Michael J. Brennan Best Paper Award from the Review of Financial Studies and the SFS Finance Cavalcade Award for Best Paper in Corporate Finance from the Society for Financial Studies. Professor Kim earned his PhD in business administration (finance) from Duke University, an AM in statistics from Harvard University, and a BBA in business administration from Seoul National University.

Roni Michaely, PhD

Professor Roni Michaely is SFI professor of finance at Geneva Finance Research Institute at the University of Geneva. Before that, he was a Finance professor at Cornell University. Professor Michaely’s research interests are in the areas of empirical corporate finance, corporate governance, entrepreneurial finance, and fintech, where he recently launched a new executive education program (https://fintech-unige.ch/). He was recently recognized as one of the most-cited people in finance, and finished serving a four-year term as an associate editor for the Journal of Finance. Professor Michaely's research has received many awards such as the Journal of Financial Economics Fama Prize for best paper, the Journal of Finance Smith Breeden Prize for distinguished paper, The Review of Financial Studies Barclays Global Investors/Michael Brennan Award. His research has appeared in such scholarly journals as the Journal of Finance, Review of Financial Studies, Journal of Financial Economics, Management Science, Review of Finance, and Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. His research has also frequently featured in the Wall Street Journal, New York Times, the Economist, Bloomberg, BusinessWeek, Forbes, and others. Michaely has given over 200 invited research talks and conference presentations around the world, and is working with scholars from the US, Europe, and Asia on research in corporate finance.

2 thoughts on “Sunset Provisions for Dual-Class Share Structures?”

  1. I agree with the authors that dual class shares have value for investors. However, I have a somewhat different take on sunset provisions. See “The Undesirability of Mandatory Time-Based Sunsets in Dual Class Share Structures: A Reply to Bebchuk and Kastiel,” https://southerncalifornialawreview.com/wp-content/uploads/2019/04/Sunset-Final-Draft.pdf . A summary of the article can be found on the Harvard Forum, https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2019/04/24/the-undesirability-of-mandatory-time-based-sunsets-in-dual-class-share-structures-a-reply-to-bebchuk-and-kastiel/ . The argument found in the article is unique in that it is based on the positive skewness of stock market returns as presented by Hendrick Bessembinder. I believe the argument is a game changer.

  2. Dual share classes, golden shares, etc. are fine. It’s just another factor to value, given the illiquidity of the firm, agency problems, etc. If the firm builds value, you should do well over the long run.

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *



By continuing to use the site, you agree to the use of cookies. more information

The cookie settings on this website are set to "allow cookies" to give you the best browsing experience possible. If you continue to use this website without changing your cookie settings or you click "Accept" below then you are consenting to this.

Close